Western Europe failed to step on the road to free economy as serious
structural distortions were left ignored. Institutional transformation in
the majority of the European countries started to stream toward the
protection of specialized interest groups under significant political
pressure. Among them, trade unions harmed the economic performance in
Europe. Unemployment policy was transmitted to restrictive government
regulation. It hampered the productivity growth directly through the
devastating establishment of collective bargaining. As a result, the gap
between the U.S. and Europe in terms of working hours per employee, widened
significantly.
Today, the EU set out an ambitious agenda having a strong desire to become
the most competitive economy in the world until 2010. Many enthusiasms have
plagued the European minds since the agenda was successfully ratified.
Today, 3 years before the final eve, it turned out that European
policymakers have not reached targets and objectives therein. The aim of
this paper is to show where exactly the Europe is lagging behind the U.S.
and how structural deficiencies undermine the ability of European countries
to sustain high rates of economic growth and increased levels of
competitiveness and prosperity.
Rapid fiscal expansion, severe ageing population pressures, rigid labor
markets and awful regulation are among the most obvious factors in European
drift away from objectives written in Lisbon Agenda. Public expenditures in
Europe are very high. The wealthiest economies such as Ireland and
Switzerland, where government spending and consumption expenditures are low
compared to stagnant European economies, enjoy a high degree of economic
freedom coupled with solid, fair and transparent institutional framework. It
is projected that increasingly ageing population will prolong fiscal
pressures and therefore post more macroeconomic risk such as a lingering
worry of public debt. Current public debt of Italy is equal to 107.8 percent
of the GDP. High and risky macroeconomic pressures are mostly the result of
state welfare-dependent ageing population through fiscal mechanisms that
cannot sustain in the long-run. Going for growth in order to emerge as the
most competitive economy in the world in such a short period of time will
certainly not meet the expectation when the persistence of structural
problems is widespread while there are no signs of recovery features
undertaken by the macroeconomic and structural policymakers.
Labor freedom in Europe is low as labor markets are marred by a persistent
rigidness and inflexibility. This is partly attributed to the inexplicit
support of the position of trade unions in collective bargaining. Labor
costs per unit are high as well as the unemployment among youth is
significant, except for Denmark, Ireland and Netherlands where statistical
rates of youth unemployment are low compared to other economies in Western
Europe. High costs of labor coupled with hard hiring and firing practices
inevitably impair the productivity growth and dynamics of firm's change as
well. The spiral of rigidness and signs of economic downturn are usually
resulted in sluggish and anemic economic growth rates. The pursuit of labor
freedom is a necessary requirement for a competitive economy.
Maintaining a 'status quo' is not a solution to achieve higher levels of
competitiveness.
Third obstacle of Lisbon goals is a heavy burden of regulation which has
turned out to be inefficient and a barrier to further capital formation, job
creation, productive behavior and doing business in general. High proportion
of administrative costs set a big limit to the reform of the business
environment in which enterprises in Western Europe operate. Rigidities and
further inflexibilities occurred after French government officially declared
its economic patriotism through which the dominance of some domestic
enterprises over foreign companies was exercised. The ease with which
businesses can secure rights to property is difficult. According to World
Bank, it takes 183 days to register and secure a private property in France.
In Ireland, it takes only 38 days. Taking the situation seriously, the
ability of business sector in most of the EU countries to compete globally
in an international perspective is further limited due to dealing with
licenses. Robust institutional framework and the difficulty of its
responsiveness to business change largely contributed to the decline of new
joint ventures that could be attained. Instead, venture companies, in most
cases, chose other more attractive locations to invest. According to IBM
Global Investment Locations Survey, less than 20 global R&D investment
projects were done in every European state while the United Kingdom was the
hottest destination for global investors in 2005. When Ronald Reagan slashed
the monopoly power of trade unions and deregulated the economy through tax
cuts and vast administrative reforms, the economy skyrocketed as well as the
business sector statistically improved the majority of its parameters. The
policymakers in the European Union should reconsider whether it makes sense
to transfer budget subsidies to certain companies that suffer from difficult
business environment conditions while the regulatory framework is floating
away and remains unreformed.
At the end, I would like to pay attention to some structural parameters in
the EU showing the reason why competitiveness and rapid global shift in the
EU seem virtually impossible in such a short time. Tax systems in the EU
have undergone dramatic changes in recent periods. The flat tax revolution
has been taking place in Eastern Europe while continually prolonged tax
codes with high progressive tax rates remained in action in the majority of
EU member states. Slovakia, Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania are young and
hopeful boomers of tomorrow. Despite being so young, the policymakers in
those countries implemented radical tax reforms and thus became the leading
reformers in Europe as well as in a global sphere. Productivity growth, the
role of free-market institutions, free enterprise, personal liberty and
economic freedom are the main requirements for economic growth. Perhaps the
most influential variable is a level of taxation that varies from time to
time, from place to place. Empirical studies have shown that highly
progressive tax rate reduce the ability of economy to sustain high growth
rates. When tax code with progressive taxation rates is in action, it poses
a twin-tracked risk. First, it degrades the productive behavior of
individuals and companies to compete and rally for growth in an enhanced
global position. The inability of knowledgeable, successful and productive
individuals is therefore very much the result of high tax rates on corporate
and individual income. Lisbon Agenda declared the need for technological
progress and investment in human capital infrastructure and innovations
while, at the same time, burdensome taxation levels through which the
explosive welfare spending is financed, sets a panel of difficulties to
technological investment and service restructuring based upon innovations.
This often parallels with uncompetitive education sector in a global
perspective. With the exception of reputed British Universities such as
Oxford and Cambridge, the highest rated university in the EU is ranked
40thin the world according to